Saturday, April 20, 2024
12:20 PM (GMT +5)

Go Back   CSS Forums > CSS Compulsory Subjects > Islamiat

Reply Share Thread: Submit Thread to Facebook Facebook     Submit Thread to Twitter Twitter     Submit Thread to Google+ Google+    
 
LinkBack Thread Tools Search this Thread
  #1  
Old Monday, December 12, 2011
killerbee's Avatar
Junior Member
 
Join Date: Oct 2011
Location: karachi
Posts: 7
Thanks: 6
Thanked 4 Times in 1 Post
killerbee is on a distinguished road
Default A Comparative Study of Zakah and Modern Taxation

I have downloaded this document from internet, and hope that it will be beneficial.






1. Introduction

Za kah is “that portion of a man’s wealth which is designated for the poor” (Sayyid Sabiq, 1991, p.1). It is also defined as: “a compulsory levy imposed on the Muslims so as to take surplus money or wealth from the compara tively well-to-do members of the Muslim Society and give it to the destitute and needy” (Zaim, 1989, p.101). Economically, za kah in theory will result in economic prosperity as za kah is paid from those who have surplus, to the poor. This will improve the poor’s purchasing power, which may lead to a higher demand on goods (Ahmad, 1977, p.80). ‘Purification’ is also among the objectives and purposes of zakah. This includes purifying the wealth of

25


the contributor because in the wealth of the relatively well-to-do, some portions of it are the right (due) of the others(1). The Islamic concept of wealth viewed that all wealth bestowed by Allah as a Trust (Ama nah). The real owner of wealth is Allah alone (Abdalati, 1980, p.128).

Conditions for za ka table assets and income are specified and determined by Islamic Sha riah. Za kah is traditionally levied not only on money, but also on commercial goods or merchandise, agricultural produce, livestock, minerals including gold, silver and treasure trove. Applying the methodology of qiya s (analogical reasoning), the emerging and increasing types of wealth in the modern times such as bank deposits and financial securities like shares and bonds are also za katable (al-Qaradawi, 1999, p.333), so as to ensure that the rightful recipients are not being denied from getting their rights as well as to ensure the society in general does not suffer due to the unfair redistribution of wealth.

Za kah shall be due on all valuable items and the ‘illah(2) for zaka ta bility is the richness (Bakar, 1998, p.3). The ‘illa h for za ka ta bility should no longer be productive property, but any property which is in excess of one’s personal use and his dependents. Accordingly, many modern forms of wealth and income since they are valuable property or ma l should be subjected for zaka h except items of personal consumption and over and above the customary needs of a person and his dependants.

The main objective of the paper is, first, to compare and contrast the concept of za kah and modern taxation especially on the legal, economic, social, ethical and spiritual aspects. Secondly, the paper aims to examine issues related to the implementation of za kah in modern time by reviewing the practices of zakah and taxation in the early Islamic period and exploring the issues in the context of Malaysia.

2. Basic Concepts of Taxation

Taxation can be defined as a compulsory payment to a government based on holdings of a tax base (Mikesell, 2003, p. 638). It is an important political and economic issue (Connolly & Munro, 1999, p. 159). For a long time, governments imposed taxes to raise revenues only to cover the cost of administration and defense, and the provision of certain services by the state, and in the case of despotic monarchs the personal expenditure of the ruler (Hanson, 1972, p.556).

Nowadays, taxes are no longer imposed solely for those purposes, but also for the purposes of furthering social and economic policy. It is a compulsory contribution by people to the state to enable it to discharge its political and economic responsibilities. Abbasi (1985, pp.60-61) viewed that state and tax are complementary and one cannot survive without the other.

Among other reasons for the imposition of taxes, as outlined in Hanson (1972, p.557) are: (i) to check the consumption of commodities regarded as harmful, at least if consumed to excess. It is for this reason that spirits and, to some extent, tobacco are


(1) al-Qur'a n, Sura h al-Ma‘a rij 70:24
(2) ‘Illah refers to ra tio decidendi. The issue of ‘illah is the most important element in Islamic law as the
ruling should be al ways attributed to ‘illah; whenever the ‘illa h exists, the rule of law will also exist and if the ‘illa h does not exist, the rule of law will also not exist ( Bakar, 1998, p.8).


heavily taxed, (ii) to redistribute labour, for instance to encourage labour to move from employments in one industry to other types of industry, and (iii) to reduce inequality of incomes.

There are two systems of taxation: (i) the proportional principle, and (ii) the progressive principle (Hanson, 1972, p.559). The former principle means that taxation should be proportional to income. This principle is supported by Adam Smith, the well- known Scottish economist, as he considered it as the most equitable method of raising revenue open to the state. It was certainly, according to Hanson (1972, p.559), more equitable than equality of payment - a fixed sum per head - as in the case of some poll
taxes(3) which were prevailing during his time(4). The latter principle (i.e. progressive
principle) suggests that the amount of tax to be paid increases more than proportionately with income (emphasis added). It can be more closely related to the ability to pay, and so where great inequality of income exists it is generally regarded as being more equitable than the proportional system, for the Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility shows that the marginal utility of £1 of income is much greater to the man with an income of £350 than to one with an income of £5000 (Hanson, 1972, p. 541).

Adam Smith, an influential Western thinker, had enunciated four canons of taxation in his book The Wea lth of Na tions (Hanson, 1972, p.541). According to Adam Smith, the amounts people paid in taxes should be equal, by which in fact he meant proportional to their incomes. This principle basically provided that every person in the society was equal and alike for the purposes of taxation. Secondly, Smith argued that there should be certainty with regard to the amount to be paid. This principle provided the detailed and known basis to the tax-payer and tax-collector. Nothing was left to the choice or pleasure of either of the two(5). Both knew what one is to pay and the other is
to collect (Abbasi, 1985, p.61). Thirdly, there should be convenience of payment and collection(6). Fourthly, economy should be observed, so that taxes should not be imposed of a kind where the cost of collections was excessive. It has been estimated that in the case of some former taxes the expenses of collection absorbed as much as 85 per cent of the yield (Hanson, 1972, p. 559).

In short, Smith describes that a sound tax should reflect the ability to pay(7), be certain and understandable, convenience to pay (to each subject) and minimum exaction (take as little from taxpayers as necessary) (Meera & Ahsan, 1992, p.214-215). In the historical context, Smith’s famous canons of taxation appear as good political advice

(3) By the poll taxes of 1378-80AD each person was not, however, equally taxed. A whole village was assessed at so much per head, but the rich paid more than the poor ( Hanson, 1972, p. 559).
(4) Abu Yusuf (731-798AD), as in Sadeq (1992, p.7 in Sadeq & Ghazali), argued for a proportional tax in
agriculture, instead of a fixed levy on land, on the ground that the former was likely to yield larger revenue and facilitate expansion of land area under cultivation. This ideas was later propagated by Adam Smith during his time.
(5) Ibn Taimiyah (as cited in Islahi, 1992, p.142 in Sadeq & Ghazali) si milarly, condemns injustice on the part of both tax payers and collectors. He says: “Very often, injustice (zulm) is done by the authorities as well as their subjects, the former demand what is not justifiable and the latter deny what is due ”.
(6) Ibn Hazm (as cited in Ghazali,1992, p.69 in Sadeq & Ghazali), was especially concerned over the nature of the tax collection system. Abusive and exploitative means of collecting taxes must be prevented. Taxes were to be collected by not transgressing the limits of Sha riah.
(7) The concept of ability to pay in the principle of taxation had been previously brought up by Abu Bakr al-
Tartusi (450H), as cited in Sadeq (1992, p.7 in Sadeq & Ghazali). It means that tax should be imposed only on the surplus income after meeting all the basic needs.


(West, 1990, p.126) and has been accepted and determined by people with their free will and consent (Abbasi, 1985, p.61).

A basic criterion for tax-structure design is the equity objective (Meera & Ahsan,
1992, p214). In another Smith’s major work, The Theory of Mora l Sentiments (1759, as cited in Muller, 1993, p.ii), he described the role of a state towards managing the financial welfare of its people: “He is certainly not a good citizen who does not wish to promote, by every means in his power, the welfare of the whole society of his fellow- citizens”. As mentioned earlier, Smith is a strong proponent of the ‘ability to pay’ concept. Tax capacity is defined by Smith (as cited in Hollander, 1973, p.279) in terms of the total annual revenue: “ The riches a nd so fa r a s power depends upon riches, the power of every country, must alwa ys be in proportion to the va lue of its a nnua l produce, the fund from which a ll taxes must ultimately be pa id” . Smith frequently clarified that (as cited in Hollander, 1973, p.204): “ It must be remembered, however, that it is the luxurious a nd not the necessa ry expense of the inferior ranks of people tha t ought ever to be ta xed” .

3. Zakah and Taxation in the Early Islamic Period

Islamic states’ revenues shall comprise of za kah, taxes and tariffs. Even though in a l-Qur’an Allah mentioned za kah, but not taxes, majority of Islamic scholars concluded that a government may impose taxes or tariffs, besides za kah. The imposition of taxation is subject to several conditions, among others, when the treasury is not having sufficient money to cover the country’s expenses (al-Qaradawi, 1999, p. 671; Hannan, n.d., p. 1). According to Ahmad (1989, p.12), Muslim jurists through the ages have accorded approval to imposition of new taxes provided the expenditures to be financed by new taxes fall in the category of essential expenditure and the tax burden is equitably distributed. It is also a requirement that the state does not spend the tax money in an extravagant or luxurious manner.

Taxation is needed and in certain situations it comes to the extent of compulsory for the state to impose taxes, where there is not enough revenues to cover for the government expenditures. This is due to zakah resources can only be utilized for specified and restricted purposes only. For many years throughout the history, governments imposed taxes because they needed to raise revenue to cover the costs of administration, national defense and security, judicial institutions, infrastructures for the purpose of public health (e.g. hospitals), public education (e.g. schools), transportation (e.g. highways), irrigation and many kinds of public facilities for the purpose of promoting social and economic policy of a state. In all these kinds of situations, the tax charge is allowed in Islam.

Ibn Taimiyah (as cited in Islahi, 1992, p.141) argues that the Shariah sources of public revenue fall under three heads as he says: “ Government revenues ba sed on the Book a nd the Sunna h a re three types, gha nima h, sa da qa h a nd fa y’” . Ghanimah refers to property which has been acquired from non-Muslims after a war, which is stated in sura t a l-Anfal of al-Qur’an. One-fifth of the spoils of war was apportioned for the state while four-fifths were generally distributed among the fighters. This was a significant source of revenue during those periods. Sa da qah here refers to za kah.


While Fa y’ is the booty surrendered by the enemy without actual fighting. It covers gifts presented to the head of state, tribute paid by enemy and financial penalties (Ahmad, 1989, p. 11; Islahi, 1992, p.145). Jizyah, kha raj, ‘ushur and treasure trove are among them. Jizyah is a per capita financial contribution that non-Muslims were expected to make for the provision of amenities and protection that they enjoyed in an Islamic state without being obligated to fight for the defense of the state (Ahmad, 1989, p. 11). Kha raj was a tax on agricultural land located outside the Arabian Peninsula in countries conquered by Muslims. ‘Ushur, on the other hand, is a type of retaliatory customs duty on goods imported by foreign merchants crossing into the Islamic state from countries where similar duty was charged from Muslim merchants. In short, it is custom duties or toll taxes imposed on traders of other countries.

According to al-Qaradawi (1999, p.671), “ if the proceeds of kha raj, ghanima and fay’ ar e sufficient, there is no need for imposing taxes, but if some sources do not exist or do not yield a sufficient a mount, other ta xes need to be levied, since the principle of usul(8)states, ‘Something without which a n obligation ca nnot be fulfilled is a lso obliga tory’” . However, in the case where for example, the tax money is collected for personal expenditure of the despotic monarchs or the ruler, it is not allowed.

In short, there is no reason why other taxes could not be collected, because after all, the purpose of za kah levy is very different from the purpose of taxation. Hannan (n.d., p.3) viewed that all sorts of taxes can be levied under the Islamic system, as long as revenues are needed for the development and defense of the country and for social welfare. Ahmad (1989, p.12) also emphasizes that the revenue (read: taxation) system of a present day state guided by Islamic teachings can differ significantly from that of the early Islamic period in respect of the composition of taxes and other details. Otherwise, some benefits of taxation difficult to derive, for example in terms of its benefit in bridging the gap between the rich and the poor in the society.

This notion is also supported by al-Qaradawi and a precedent case during Caliph Umar b. al-Khattab, where non-Muslims (i.e. Christians of Banu Taghlib) during his time requested to drop jizyah and impose another tax with the name of Sa daqa h, However, it must be borne in mind that tax is more on a matter of societal obligation, however za kah is undoubtedly the right of Allah, and thus it must come first before other obligations are being fulfilled.

4. Zakah vs. Taxation


Shaltut (as cited in al-Qaradawi, 1999, p. 698) argued that taxes could not be counted as zakah. His view was that since za kah is a financial act of worship, it is far from being similar to taxes. Although there are certain similarities between taxation and za kah, the differences are much greater. Taxation and zakah differ in their respective legislative sources, in their theoretical foundation, their objectives, rates, exemptions, and in their expenditures. The paper proceeds with the comparison between za kah and taxation.



(8) Usul refers to the science of fiqh methodology and axiomatic system.


4.1 Concepts
Al-Qaradawi (1999, p.693) asserts that there is no and should never be any replacement for the term za kah. The term za kah, should be used as it is, and Muslims should not try to find an equivalent term with it, because there is none. The term zakah carries unique meanings and significance, and translating it could result to a divert in its meanings and purposes from its original context. Majeed (1993, p.21) further argues that:

“ ...a lthough za ka h ca n be said to be a kind of ta x a nd the za ka h la ws ca nbe r eferred to as a system of ta xa tion, za ka h significa nces a re many a nd it ca nnot therefore be compar ed to the existing secula r system of taxa tion. Therefore, it is best tha t the word za ka h is not tra nsla ted and tha t Muslims should use the term za kah itself and expla in its concept to non Muslims” .

Any wealth below the nisab is exempted from the za kah obligation. The concept of exemption in the case of taxation is applicable only when the government or tax authorities specifically stipulate it. The concept of yearly assessment (i.e. ha wl) in zakah applies to most types of wealth, excluding agriculture produce, mineral extracted and earned income

Since the obligatory nature of za kah has been prescribed in the revealed doctrine of a l-Qur’an, zakah system must be upheld as a levy sanctioned by Allah on Muslims. Taxation is also liable, but not for the same reason as za kah. Taxation is a levy sanctioned by government on citizens (individuals or businesses) of a particular state through the federal laws. It is a man-made system, and as such, its source of regulation is determined by the government of the time.

The conditions of taxable assets and income plus the way to disburse tax is the prerogative of the government at the time. The same argument follows in terms of the tax structure, its rates and allowable deductions, among others. Zaim (1989, p.110) reiterated that (1) the rate and the way of payment of za kah which are clear and definite, cannot be altered: but tax is relatively changeable, and, (3) the methods of distribution and spending of za kah is definite, while tax is not. Taxation law can be amended, and can even be abolished, depending on the availability of surplus or deficit in the government’s fiscal system. It should also be noted that it is relatively easier for the government to make amendments to taxation law as compared to the za kah law since the former does not have any direct relationship with revealed doctrines.

Comparing za kah with progressive taxation, za kah was claimed as having a wider base than progressive taxation; it is imposed not only on income, but also on idle assets. The proceeds of za kah will benefit mainly and directly the poor and the needy. Hence, it will consequently raise the propensity to consume (Metwally as cited in Zaim, 1989, p.111). Zakah is also levied on productive wealth, but tax can be levied both on productive assets as well as on consumption expenditure.

4.2 Legal Impacts
Based on the Islamic history, during the Caliphate of Abu Bakar, a war was declared on those disputing the za kah obligation. As for the one who refrains from paying it without denying its obligation, he would be guilty of committing a sin. It is the


ruler’s duty to take za kah from the defaulter by force and rebuke him, provided he does not collect more than the stipulated amount. In the views of Iman Ahmad ibn Hanbal and Imam Abu Hanifah, the ruler could take half of the defaulter’s money, in addition to the calculated amount of za kah, as a punishment (al-Qaradawi, 1999, p.668).

In modern taxation, tax planning is normally provided by tax consultants for individuals or companies to plan their tax liability. This is also known as tax avoidance. Tax avoidance basically means playing with the tax rules, and it is regarded as a legal activity, provided it falls within the rules and regulations. Its legality is based on the idea that every taxpayer has the right not to attract tax and to arrange his tax affair. Taxpayer would and should take advantage of any lacuna or loopholes within the tax rules.

While tax avoidance is allowed, tax evasion is not. Methods of evasion include suppressing the taxable receipts; and claiming deductions for expenditure not incurred. Evading payment of tax due by any person involves elements of offence in it. If caught, the defaulter has to pay the tax evaded and penalties(9).

Unlike taxation, it is morally and Islamically improper for Muslims to minimize their za kah liability whether through avoidance or evasion. It is the spirit of za kah that it should be paid on the real net worth of a person’s wealth. Evasion is a real possibility in tax, but zakah is paid by the believer as a form of worship (Zaim, 1989, p.111). In a pure Islamic state, such tricks and behaviors would be a serious crime against the society and thus, a punishable offence. It is against the spirit of Quranic injunctions since the offender is trying to deny Allah’s rights. In the absence of an Islamic state, the individual has to be careful, as Allah knows our deepest thoughts and intentions.

In some Islamic countries, certain preventive measures in the form of incentives for the zakah payer have been undertaken by its government. For instance, in Malaysia, the tax authority under the federal government grant a tax rebate, if a Muslim had paid za kah. As an example; a Muslim made za kah payment to the authority of RM1000, this RM1000 is treated as a rebate of tax that is set against his total tax that is due. In other words, he obtains a 100 percent relief for the za kah payment. This is considered as a pro-active effort towards the development of the za kah system. This will partly minimize the burden among the Muslims for having to pay both za kah and tax.

4.3 Economic and Social Impacts
Za kah occupies an important place in Islamic economics. It serves as a unique mechanism of compulsory transfers of income and wealth from the haves to the have nots in the community (Miah, 1992, p.153). Through this, each and every individual in the society are assured of minimum means of livelihood, which provides social security system in an Islamic society (Ahmad, 1989, p.6).

Throughout history, whenever Muslims truthfully applied the system of za kah, as ordained by Allah and His messenger, the splendid objectives of za kah were fulfilled


(9) Ibn Taimiyah (as cited in Islahi, 1992, p. 142 in Sadeq & Ghazali), forbids tax evasion, especially when the tax is levied collectively on a group or community, even when the tax is unjust. The reason for this i s that, if a person evades his share of tax, that share will fall on the others in the group, who will thus have an even greater and more unjust burden to carry.


and its great efforts appeared within the lives of the individuals and the society. One excellent example is during the Caliphate of Umar b. Abdul Aziz whereby the zakah system was so successful that it became difficult to find even one needy person to receive the za kah collection. This shows how za kah, if implemented properly could make wonders to the society. Sayyid Sabiq (1991, p.xvi) has brought up this point very eloquently when he said:

“ Wha t is rema rka ble a bout zaka h is that it finishes a job tha t taxa tion, to begin with, ca nnot a ccomplish” .

One similarity between za kah and taxation is whereby both have to be paid though no direct and equivalent economic benefit obtained by the za kah and tax payer. Zakah payers are expected to get the reward and the returns in the hereafter while tax payers may receive some service in return but there is no direct co-relation (Hannan, n.d., p.1).

Hanson (1972, p.546-8) identified various negative economic effects of taxation. These include a deterrent to work, a deterrent to saving, a deterrent to enterprise, taxation may also encourage inflation, and diversion of economics resources. As such, taxation, above a certain level, can be economically disadvantageous. Similarly, Ibn Khaldun (1332-1406 AD) (as cited in Sadeq, 1992, p.7, in Sadeq & Ghazali) argued that work efforts will be affected by high taxes resulting a decrease in production and population (due to emigration), which will eventually decrease tax revenue by decreasing the tax base. Ibn Khaldun’s assertion is strongly agreed by many Islamic scholars such as Siddiqi (1992b, p.48 in Sadeq & Ghazali), where when government (consumption) expenditure increases and more taxes are levied, economic growth is adversely affected, eventually leading to a decline (see also Issawi, 1992, p.224 in Sadeq & Ghazali).

The additional (or excessive) taxation would produce economically harmful results that outweigh the gain to the community from the use of the money raised by taxation (Hanson, 1972, p.549). The same suggestion had been provided much earlier by Ibn Khaldun (1332-1406 AD), (as cited by Siddiqi, 1992a, p.23 in Sadeq & Ghazali):

“ The most powerful fa ctor contributing to popula tion a nd civilization is minimiza tion of the qua ntity of ta xes on the people to the extent feasible. This gives incentive to people as they feel confidence by rea lizing the benefits of civiliza tion” .

Tax burden is able to be transferred by the tax payer to the consumer or producer (Zaim, 1989, p.111). However, in za kah, there is no such transfer of za kah burden. Al- Maqrizi (1364-1441 AD), (as cited in Sadeq, 1992, p.7, in Sadeq & Ghazali) analysed the problem of tax burden. According to him, if tax is not efficiently handled, tax burden may be shifted to consumers, whereas it is supposed to be borne by the producers and business men from the profit income. A consequence, according to him, is the fall in demand for the goods concerned because of their higher tax adjusted prices, which in turn affects the suppliers and the economy as a whole.

There are many impacts of za kah which include the incentive to produce, incentive to invest, incentive to save, incentive to consume, playing a role in redistribution of income/assets, incentive to work, as a control of business fluctuation, and as a


redirection of investment (Ataul Haq, 1993, p.12-20; Miah, 1992, p.121; Ahmad, 1989, p.20-25). Za kah also has a multiplier effect to the economy; some Muslim economists believe that a certain amount of zakah funds invested according to the overall production priorities of an economy would benefit the poor in particular and the economy, in general, through its multiplier effect on employment and incomes (Zaim,
1989, p.117). In this way it would gradually eliminate poverty instead of providing recurring financial support to the same set of people. Consequently, employment and income will be increased in the economy thereby increasing the standard of living of the people and eventually it would enhance the aggregate volume of za kah collection.

If za kah is properly managed, the government may be relieved from significant social welfare expenditure. Thus, resort to taxation can be kept to a minimum in an Islamic economy. In addition, Sadeq (1992, p.9, as cited in Sadeq & Ghazali) rightly emphasized that za kah is a sub-set and integral part of the social security system which is built in the Islamic economic system, to help the less-priviledged group such as poor, needy, unemployed, orphans, handicapped and so on. In a more elaborate manner, Mawdudi (1975, p.35) regarded za kah as, in fact, the best form of insurance for the society and destroys all the evils which arise from the absence of any regular arrangement for collective help and cooperation. Mawdudi pointed out that what really forces a man, in the capitalistic system, to accumulate wealth and invest it in profitable business and bring into existence institutions like the life insurance, is that under this system every one’s life is wholly dependant on his own means. This view has also been emphasized by Sharif (1976, p.171) that za kah in the Muslim constitution of the Caliphate days was so comprehensive and broad-based that it not only promoted socialistic redistribution of wealth but also tended to create a healthy non-capitalistic frame of mind and a collective spirit.

4.4 Ethical and Spiritual Impacts
Al-Ghazali (1983, p.53-73), in his treatise Ihya ‘Ulum a l-Din has outlined eight
inward attitudes and duties that are incumbent on those who seek, through payment of their alms (read za kah), the way that leads to the Hereafter. These include (1) understand the purpose and significance of za kah, (2) payment at proper time, (3) give in secret , (4) give openly, (5) avoid taunting and hurting, (6) adopt humility, (7) give the best and the dearest and (8) seek the worthy and deserving.

Za kah, according to al-Ghazali, is a measure to test our degree of love to Allah. Al- Quran considers possession of wealth a trying test, and not a token of virtuous excellence or privileged nobility or a means of exploitation(10) (Abdalati, 1980, p.128). Al-Ghazali (1997, p.80-81) argued that:

“ Our property which is ver y dea r to us, is God’s trust deposited with us. Therefore, it is necessa ry tha t they should be sa crificed in His cause, and they should be utilized for seeking His plea sure. If you suffer a loss in them, you should not sta rt crying and wa iling a nd you should not consider that it wa s your personal property tha t has been ta ken a wa y from you, beca use compared to you Alla h is the more rightful owner and


(10) al-Qura n, Sura h al-An’am 6: 165.


He ha s the right to use it in a ny wa y He likes. If you a re tested by a n increa se in them, then you should not hesita te to undertake jihad when ca lled upon to do so, a nd you should not turn away from obedience to Alla h on a ccount of them” (11).

In Islam, the real owner of wealth is God alone and the proprietor is simply an appointed agent and a mere trustee (Abdalati, 1980, p.130). In explaining the concept of trust, al-Ghazali (1983, p.73) mentioned that in the eyes of Sha riah, trust has a very broad sense. This word contains an ocean of meaning, but underneath it is the sense of responsibility, the sense of having to appear before Allah and to account for one’s actions. The details regarding the concept of a ma nah (trust and responsibility) in Islam as provided by the ha dith:

“ Everyone of you is a gua rdia n a nd everyone will be a sked about his subjects. The Ima m is a gua rdian. He will be a sked a bout his subjects. A man is the gua rdian of the persons in his household. He is a nswera ble a bout them. A woma n is the gua rdia n of her husba nd’s house. She will be a sked a bout her responsibility. The serva nt is the guardia n of the articles of his ma ster. He is a nswera ble a bout this responsibility of his” (al-Bukhari)

Za kah is also considered as an expression of gratitude to God’s bounties. Zakah payment should be done once it becomes due and should not be procrastinated. The best is that we perform the duty secretly, unless we want others to follow suit our good deeds. Most importantly, we should not feel arrogant and we should not hurt the feelings of the recipient. In terms of giving the best and the dearest, we can apply this in the context of how we perceived wealth and money. Al-Ghazali (1997, p.80) emphasized that wealth given by Allah is a trust (the concept of trustworthy). Proprietors are constantly reminded of the fact that they are in reality mere agents appointed by God to administer their holdings. However, Islam did not prevent the Muslims from attaining wealth and endeavoring for material improvements through lawful means.

In terms of distributing zakah, we must ensure that the most worthy and deserving in the society will benefit from our duty fulfillment. Accordingly, Abdalati (1980, p.128) emphasized that the proprietor must always be ready to spend in the way of God and to contribute to worthy causes. It makes him responsive to the needs of the society and gives him an important role to play, a sacred mission to fulfill.

In the case of taxation, the element of reluctance and rancour is underlying. This is so because tax payer is not moved by the conviction that the levy is from Allah, who will then recompensate him for it (Shad, 1986, p.44). Even in the so-called advanced societies where the role of taxation in the modern-day state is very well understood, there is a perennial conflict of interests between the tax giver and the recipient. The question ‘Why should I support social programs?’ continues popping up in different forms and debates” (Sayyid Sabiq, 1991, p.xvi).



(11) a l-Qura n, Sura h al-Anfal 8: 27-28.


The above situation could negatively impact the smooth-running of the tax system, plus, it would affect the accomplishment of the tax objectives. Even though various measures have been undertaken through various means of transfer payments, for instance, through providing facilities to the people, taxation system is still unable to bridge the said gap, until and unless moral aspects is incorporated and inculcated within the mind and hearts of the payers. Thus, ideally, in order to ensure the taxation system derives its utmost benefit; its compliance should come along with the moral ethics and spiritual involvement of the payer. This perhaps could help in achieving the indirect benefits from taxation.

Zakah, on the other hand, does not carry such problems because it does not ignore the human context of human relations. It is man who is at the heart of its program. It also involves spiritual implications as fully and comprehensively as any other mode and manner of worship prescribed as fundamental pillar of Islam would do (Abbasi, 1985, p.59).

Taxation may not be significant to the tax payer other than it saves him from fines and prison term (Majeed, 1993, p.21). Taxation has primarily legal and economic incentives and implications, as compared to moral and spiritual incentives, unlike in the case of zakah. Modern taxation merely looks at the compliance of a citizen to his or her country’s laws and regulations. This also has been supported by Zaim (1989, p.110), where he stated that taxation is a financial responsibility while za kah is a religious duty and worship in terms of finance.

Despite the fact that taxation is a social obligation without having special sense of gratitude to Allah or to obtain nearness to Allah, it has to be borne in mind that as a citizen in a particular country, once the state imposed tax, as long as it is for legitimate reasons, and will be used in a legitimate ways, Muslims will become obliged and responsible to pay tax imposed on them.

Majeed (1993, p.21) had addressed the issue that zakah has important moral and spiritual dimensions as compared to tax, which is only concerned with the monetary effects:

“ ...in most situation, ta xpayers pa y their ta x relucta ntly a nd try to seek every deduction they ca n possibly get. On the other ha nd, za ka h givers a re supposed to give their zaka h willingly. They should feel eager to fulfil their obliga tion of giving za ka h to plea se Allah. This is beca use za ka h giving is a n a ct of submission” .

4.5 Issues on the Implementation of Zakah and Taxation: the Case of Malaysia
From the preceding section, it shows that an Islamic state has the right to charge other levies, besides zakah, on its citizens. However, as reflected in most Muslim countries’ fiscal systems, they seem to regard taxation as more important compared to za kah. Taxation system becomes an integral part of the fiscal system, whereas zakah becomes just a voluntary institution. This prevailing practice in Muslims countries could be contributed by the colonialist influence over the Muslims lands. Many contemporary Islamic scholars raise the above issues and try to promote a true Islamic institution such as za kah to play its prominent role as a divine practice in true Muslim societies.


Al-Qaradawi, in his monumental work, Fiqh a l-Za kah (La w of Za ka h), argued that taxes do not make up for zakah, since za kah, as pillar of Islam, must not be forgotten in the actual practice. Sincere Muslims must pay za kah in addition to taxes which they are obliged to pay by law. This is one way of striving for the re-establishment of this religion on earth. Al-Qaradawi (1999, p.700) further asserts that the legal and economic situation in Muslim countries must be brought back to compliance with the Islamic system. Without enormous effort to reform Muslim societies under the guidance of the Islamic system, Muslims will remain financially, psychologically, and socially burdened.

Nik Hassan (1991, p.217), in describing the position of za kah in Malaysian fiscal management, had pointed out that:

“ There is no synchroniza tion between these two functions. The only relation between za ka h and the country’s fisca l ma na gement is through the provision in the ta x system tha t zaka h pa yers can obta in ta x rebate for the amount contributed a s za ka h. Thus, the za ka h system ha s no significa nt place in the Mala ysian fiscal system. It is seen solely as a
‘religious’ activity, and the running of the economy is considered a s a
munda ne responsibility. Islam is seen a s a religion in the Western sense a nd not a s a complete system tha t governs the whole spectrum of the country’s ma na gement” .

The above can be attributed to the historical background of the Federal Constitution in Malaysia. The Constitution recognized religious affairs as state matters, rather than federal matters (refer to the Ninth schedule of Malaysian Federal Constitution). Thus, the administration of zakah in Malaysia is under the jurisdiction of the respective states or the prerogative of the rulers (Sultan) of the respective states, except in Federal Territory whereby the zakah law and administration are governed by the Federal government (Bakar, 1998, p.13). Consequently, all aspects pertaining to the administration of za kah are handled by the states through its respective Ma jlis Aga ma
Isla m Negeri (State Islamic Religious Councils)(12), while the fiscal management of the
country is a federal matter.

In other states except for Federal Territory, the most that the Federal government can do is basically to coordinate the za kah matters amongst the states, but they have no ultimate power to intervene into the respective states’ za kah matters, in specific or religious matters, in general. Even though the Federal Territory did establish Department of Islamic Development (i.e. JAKIM) under the Prime Minister’s Department to coordinate and bring some form of uniformity into the administration of Islam in Malaysia, its function remains purely advisory in nature. In addition to that, the recently established Department of Zakah, Waqaf and Hajj also has a very limited role in monitoring the za kah practices in Malaysia.



(12) There are a total of fourteen State Islamic Religious Councils (SIRCs). One for each of the thirteen states and one for the Federal Territory of Kuala Lumpur, Labuan and Putrajaya. These SIRCs have a unique status in that they are not part of the Federal or State government (Pusat Pungutan Zakah, n.d., p.5).


Even though each state has its own state enactment which outlines the rules and regulations pertaining to za kah, it is very unfortunate that they are still lagging behind in terms of the law enforcement. A state government is apparently a less credible authority (as compared to federal government) in terms of the enforcement of laws. This is one of the many reasons contributing to this phenomenon. As a consequence of the above, za kah become just as a voluntary payment system. However, taxation is a highly regulated system enforced by the Federal government. Proper penalty can be imposed on the tax defaulters, and as such the compliance to the tax regulation has been perceived as more important as compared to the compliance to za kah laws.

In terms of incentive the Malaysian government has provided at least two incentives in their effort to promote za kah payment. Firstly, as discussed earlier, the tax authority under the federal government granted an income tax rebate, for individual Muslim who had paid za kah to SIRCs. Secondly, for companies, in the 2005 Malaysian Government Budget, it had been announced that any za kah which is paid by company to SIRCs will be granted as an allowable deduction in the computation of the corporate tax. However, the amount of deduction is limited to 2.5 per cent of the aggregate income.

The above exemption is very minimal. Abdul Rahman (2005, p.7) argued that this so-called ‘partial rebate’ for business entities should be replaced by full corporate tax rebate, in the same way rebate be granted to individual Muslims who paid za kah. He further explained that:

“ If government allows compa nies that pa y za ka h on business wea lth to claim reba te from their ta x lia bility, this will consequently ea se their financia l burden. Furthermore, the tax r eba te will serve a s a n incentive for Muslim majority owned companies which have not pa id in the past to pa y za ka h on business wealth” .

This argument, however, need to be studied thoroughly, if it were to be enforced. One of the possible repercussions, according to Amin (2003, p.19), is that the government would relinquish a material sum in annual income tax from the business sector.

5. Conclusion

The paper indicates that za kah greatly differs from the taxation system. Za kah aims not only to achieve religious merit, but also aims to become part of the modern state fiscal policies and shares a greater role in removing inequalities in society. The paper argues that there may be lack of proper implementation of za kah in Muslim countries and, thus, limits the success of the noble aims of the za ka h system. The paper indicates the urgent need for education and political will of modern governments in order to ensure the success and survival of the zaka h system. Further studies are needed to empirically document the successes and shortcomings of the implementation of za kah in modern Muslim countries and evaluate factors that may influence or impede the implementation of za kah. Studies are also greatly needed to evaluate the level of knowledge of za kah, especially among the Muslims, in order to assess future education needs and strategies to enhance the knowledge about zakah.
Reply With Quote
The Following 4 Users Say Thank You to killerbee For This Useful Post:
azeegum (Tuesday, December 13, 2011), kalo (Monday, December 16, 2013), shah24 (Thursday, December 15, 2011), very special 1 (Tuesday, December 13, 2011)
Reply


Posting Rules
You may not post new threads
You may not post replies
You may not post attachments
You may not edit your posts

BB code is On
Smilies are On
[IMG] code is On
HTML code is Off
Trackbacks are On
Pingbacks are On
Refbacks are On


Similar Threads
Thread Thread Starter Forum Replies Last Post
Islamic Information safdarmehmood Islamiat 4 Thursday, June 28, 2018 08:09 AM
A Guide to Islamic Banking Surmount Economics 28 Sunday, September 28, 2008 01:50 AM


CSS Forum on Facebook Follow CSS Forum on Twitter

Disclaimer: All messages made available as part of this discussion group (including any bulletin boards and chat rooms) and any opinions, advice, statements or other information contained in any messages posted or transmitted by any third party are the responsibility of the author of that message and not of CSSForum.com.pk (unless CSSForum.com.pk is specifically identified as the author of the message). The fact that a particular message is posted on or transmitted using this web site does not mean that CSSForum has endorsed that message in any way or verified the accuracy, completeness or usefulness of any message. We encourage visitors to the forum to report any objectionable message in site feedback. This forum is not monitored 24/7.

Sponsors: ArgusVision   vBulletin, Copyright ©2000 - 2024, Jelsoft Enterprises Ltd.